Pillar 2: tax competition in low-income countries and substance-based income exclusion

被引:3
|
作者
Perry, Victoria J. [1 ,2 ]
机构
[1] Said Business Sch, Ctr Business Taxat, Oxford, England
[2] Univ Oxford, Said Business Sch, Taxat, Ctr Business Taxat, Pk End St, Oxford OX1 1HP, England
关键词
economic development; globalisation; taxation of international business;
D O I
10.1111/1475-5890.12318
中图分类号
F8 [财政、金融];
学科分类号
0202 ;
摘要
Pillar 2 of the OECD's global tax reform proposal will have significant direct and indirect impacts for low-income developing countries (LICs). Most interesting and problematic is the question as to how the global anti-base erosion (GloBE) rules for a proposed global minimum effective tax will affect tax competition behaviour in LICs, and how LICs should respond when a critical mass of higher-income economies adopt the new structure. Most LICs are source-only countries, and they are very much in competition to attract foreign direct investment. Do LICs want to continue to compete using the tax system to the extent possible, to step back from that competition, or to take some intermediate course? Pillar 2 does not itself change a country's desired position on the competition spectrum - it merely affects how, and to what extent, that position can still be obtained. This paper posits that LICs should adopt qualified domestic minimum top-up taxes, and that this will not itself have a negative impact on their competitiveness. The primary focus of the paper, however, is on the design of the substance-based income exclusion (carve-out), examining the following three questions. Should the GloBE have been designed without a carve-out? Would there have been a better way of designing it? How will LICs be affected? The paper concludes that, as little real advantage is likely to accrue to LICs from intangible assets, minimising tax competition for those assets will have relatively little impact on them; and that, from an economic efficiency standpoint, shifting the tax burden away from a normal return and toward economic rents - albeit imperfectly - is a reasonable solution.
引用
收藏
页码:23 / 36
页数:14
相关论文
共 50 条
  • [31] Implementing microbicides in low-income countries
    Gengiah, Tanuja N.
    Karim, Quarraisha Abdool
    BEST PRACTICE & RESEARCH CLINICAL OBSTETRICS & GYNAECOLOGY, 2012, 26 (04) : 495 - 501
  • [32] Psychotropic drugs in low-income countries
    Dharmawardene, Vajira
    Menkes, David B.
    LANCET PSYCHIATRY, 2014, 1 (07): : 490 - 492
  • [33] Treatment of Prolactinomas in Low-Income Countries
    Kruljac, Ivan
    Kirigin, Lora Stanka
    Strinovic, Mateja
    Marinkovic, Jelena
    Pecina, Hrvoje Ivan
    Cerina, Vatroslav
    Stipic, Darko
    Vrkljan, Andmilan
    INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF ENDOCRINOLOGY, 2015, 2015
  • [34] Mpox prevention in low-income countries
    Yang, Xin Yu
    Zhang, Gong Jie
    Zhou, Ya Bin
    SCIENCE, 2024, 386 (6725) : 981 - 982
  • [35] Operational research in low-income countries
    Horstick, Olaf
    Sommerfeld, Johannes
    Kroeger, Axel
    Ridley, Robert
    LANCET INFECTIOUS DISEASES, 2010, 10 (06): : 369 - 370
  • [36] Low-Income Countries And Repurposed Drugs
    Cvek, Boris
    HEALTH AFFAIRS, 2015, 34 (11) : 2004 - 2004
  • [37] Critical care in low-income countries
    Baker, Tim
    TROPICAL MEDICINE & INTERNATIONAL HEALTH, 2009, 14 (02) : 143 - 148
  • [38] The pricing of pharmaceuticals in low-income countries
    J. Rovira
    The European Journal of Health Economics, 2002, 3 (4) : 223 - 224
  • [39] Women with cancer in low-income countries
    Narod, S. A.
    CURRENT ONCOLOGY, 2017, 24 (04) : 217 - 219
  • [40] Obstetric Ultrasonography in Low-income Countries
    Seffah, Joseph D.
    Adanu, Richard M. K.
    CLINICAL OBSTETRICS AND GYNECOLOGY, 2009, 52 (02): : 250 - 255